You are viewing a complimentary preview of this book. For options to unlock the full book, please login or visit our catalog to create a FlatWorld Account and see purchase options.
Economic Analysis of Social Issues

v2.0 Alan Grant

1.4 A Brief Introduction to Collective Action Problems

Now that you understand the concepts of scarcity, trade-offs, and incentives, we can preview the kinds of social problems you’ll study throughout this book.

Suppose a huge crowd packs a stadium to see Taylor Swift perform. When the performance begins, everyone is sitting. Then a single fan in the front row stands. When she does, she obstructs the view of two or three fans behind her. Those fans stand, too, obstructing the view of another six or seven fans behind them. Before you know it, the entire audience is standing, and they remain this way for the entire show.

This is a very interesting situation! Every individual can improve his or her view by standing. But when everybody stands, nobody can see any better than they could when they were all sitting. The only thing the audience gets for its trouble is a tired back from standing for hours on a concrete floor.

If, hypothetically, the audience could vote to either sit or stand, sitting would be the likely winner. But it is unlikely that an audience will put this to a vote, and it is unlikely that members of the audience will unilaterally forgo what is in their best interests as individuals (namely, standing) and choose to act in the best interest of the group, or collectively. For that reason, problems like this are referred to as collective action problems. A exists when naturally occurring incentives encourage sufficient numbers of people to act in a way that makes everybody worse off. Simply put, individual trade-offs are different than the trade-offs for society as a whole.

The world is full of collective action problems. In fact, many if not most of the toughest problems society faces today are some type of collective action problem. We’ll devote quite a bit of time and paper convincing you of this in the remainder of this book.

The general trouble with collective action problems is that no individual has any incentive to act in the best interests of the group. In other words, private incentives are not properly aligned with collective, or social, goals. In cases like these, individuals may be powerless to solve the problem through individual action. Under those circumstances, we may need a more powerful entity to alter incentives so that individuals are guided to make choices that are in the best interest of society. In our stadium example, that entity might be a fire marshal who orders everyone to sit. In society as a whole, that entity is often, but not always, the government. When a collective action problem exists, the government often has the ability to guide behaviors in ways that make the world better off.

Before steam power, men were paid to tow cargo boats upstream. Who, in this replica of Ilya Repin’s Volga Boatmen, is earning a paycheck but not pulling his freight?

Sculptural replica of Ilya Repin’s “Volga Boatmen,” depicting men towing a cargo barge upriver.

However, it is important to note that not all problems are collective action problems. It is also important to note that often, individual and collective incentives line up quite nicely. (We’ll spend a great deal of time talking about an example of this in Chapter 5 “Free Exchange: Individual and International Trade”.) In these situations, government intervention may actually make the world a worse place rather than a better one. So, a big part of your job as students of the economy is to ask first under what circumstances the government’s attempts to solve problems can potentially make the world better off, and second, what kinds of policies might be necessary to realize that potential.

Key Takeaways

  1. Many social problems are manifestations of collective action problems. 

  2. A collective action problem exists when the members of a group have incentives to act in ways that are beneficial to the individual but detrimental to the group as a whole: Private incentives are misaligned with social goals. 

  3. In many cases, collective action problems can be overcome by government action.

Review Questions

  1. John is a member of a group working to achieve a goal. But every member of the group has an incentive to skip the group’s long and tedious meetings, and that skipping makes the group less likely to succeed. This kind of economic problem is known as a               problem.

  2. Because collective action problems are difficult to solve, society often               .

    1. asks the benevolent social planner to step in and fix things

    2. asks the government to step in and fix things

    3. succeeds in solving them by asking its members  to forgo their own best interests and work for the greater good

    4. collective action problems are actually not difficult to solve

Problems and Applications

  1. Everybody in a residential high-rise building owns his or her own condominium. One day the elevator breaks. Discuss the collective action problem that fixing the elevator presents. In the real world, how do high-rise condo owners typically overcome that problem? Is that typical real-world solution fair to people who live on the first floor compared to people who live on the top floor?

  2. Your philosophy professor always grades exams on a curve, so that the top score in class becomes an A. The morning of a big exam, one of your classmates makes the following suggestion to the class: “Let’s all leave our papers blank. That way, even though we’ll all get zeros, everyone will get an A.” Discuss the collective action problem this situation might present.

  3. Look at a depiction of Ilya Repin’s Volga Boatmen in the photo above. The faster this team of men moves their cargo upstream, the more they’ll all earn. Discuss the collective action problem this presents to the team. Explain how individual incentives fail to align with social goals. Can you think of a solution to this problem?