You are viewing a complimentary preview of this book. For options to unlock the full book, please log in or visit our catalog to create a FlatWorld Account and see purchase options.
Principles of Microeconomics

v4.0 Libby Rittenberg, Alan Grant, and Timothy Tregarthen

1.3 The Field of Economics

Learning Objectives

  1. Identify the distinguishing characteristics of the economic way of thinking.

  2. Distinguish between microeconomics and macroeconomics.

You are now familiar with the building blocks of all of economics: scarcity, choice, and opportunity cost. In this section, we’ll look at economics as a field of study. We begin with the characteristics that distinguish economics from other social sciences.

The Economic Way of Thinking

Economists study choices that scarcity requires us to make. But all social scientists are interested in choices. An anthropologist might study the choices of ancient peoples: Will we be nomadic hunter-gatherers, or will we raise crops and live in permanent settlements? Likewise, a political scientist might study the choices of legislatures; a psychologist might study how people choose a mate; a sociologist might study the factors that have led to an increase in single-parent households. So, if everybody studies choices, what is it that separates economics from these other social sciences?

Three features distinguish the economic approach to choice from the approaches taken in other social sciences:

  1. Economists give special emphasis to the role of opportunity costs in their analysis of choices.

  2. Economists assume that individuals make self-interested choices in order to attain some clearly defined objective—a process called optimization. Optimization can be interpreted as maximizing (making as large as possible) the value of desirable things or minimizing (making as small as possible) the value of undesirable things.

  3. Economists argue that individuals pay attention to the consequences of small changes in the levels of the activities they pursue; that individuals achieve their objectives through incremental decisions about pursuing a bit more or a bit less of their activities.

The emphasis economists place on opportunity cost, the idea that people make choices in order to achieve the ideal level of a clear objective, and a focus on the effects of small changes are ideas of great power. They constitute the core of economic thinking. The next three sections examine these ideas in greater detail.

Opportunity Costs Are Important

Fireworks, schmireworks. Come spend your Independence Day with me, your obedient servant, A. Ham.

Photo of a closeup of the logo from the musical Hamilton. It has an “H” then a star with a man standing on top and pointing upward followed by the letter “M”.

If doing one thing requires giving up another, then the value of the alternatives we face can affect our choices. Economists argue that an understanding of opportunity cost is crucial to understanding the choices people make.

As the value or number of available alternatives changes, economists expect to see individual choices change—and change in predictable ways! The surprise announcement that Disney+ would air the original Broadway recording of Hamilton over the 2020 July 4th weekend changed, for millions, the opportunity cost of spending that weekend at the lake. An unexpectedly warm winter day might change your opportunity cost of going to class; your econ professor likely expects lower attendance when the weather is particularly delightful. In the same vein, a high income makes it more costly to take a day off; economists expect highly paid individuals to work more hours than those who are not paid so well. In each of these examples, and in millions more each day, the emphasis economists place on opportunity cost helps us better understand peoples’ choices by pushing us to think about the relative values of the alternatives they face.

Self-Interested Individuals Optimize

Pop! Goes the Econ: Ferris Bueller Optimizes

Ferris Bueller desperately needs a day off! Locate and explain the illustrations of opportunity cost and optimization in this clip. Bonus points if you can read ahead and pick out the marginal analysis!

What motivates people as they make choices? Perhaps more than anything else, it is the economist’s answer to this question that distinguishes economics from other fields.

Economists assume that individuals, first and foremost, pursue their own self-interest—doing things that make them, as individuals, better off; avoiding things that make them worse off. Economists assume that in chasing those rainbows, people make choices that will ultimately bring them the greatest possible benefits, given the constraints they face. 

Economists assume, for example, that the owners of business firms try to maximize their profits. That assumption gives economists power to predict how firms in an industry will respond to changes in the markets where they operate. For example, as new U.S. tariffs (a fancy word for taxes) on imported steel and aluminum drove up prices for those metals in early 2018, economists were not surprised to see heavy users of those metals, such as Harley-Davidson Motor Company, shuttering U.S. plants and shifting production to countries where tariff rates were lower and steel cheaper. 

A solid understanding of economics can help you explain this man’s portion sizes!

Photo of a larger man sitting at a table with his mouth open. On the table is a large amount of burgers, fries, and raw  vegetables.

Assumptions about the profit-maximizing behavior of business firms give economists great power to explain how firms behave in the real world. Likewise, assumptions about the goals of people who buy products (often referred to as consumers) shed similar light on those peoples’ behavior. Of course, consumers don’t maximize profits. Instead, economists assume that individual consumers make choices in order to maximize their satisfaction, or utility. That utility-maximization assumption, again, gives economists great power to explain all kinds of interesting consumer behavior—like why birthday celebrants often prefer cash to gifts, and why we tend to overeat when the restaurant we choose happens to offer a buffet.

A cautionary note: Study economics long enough, and sooner or later you’ll be accused of  endorsing greed. But good economists know that there’s a difference between self-interest and selfishness. People clearly gain satisfaction by helping others—just ask any parent, or anyone who has ever volunteered their time or donated to a charity. So, when economists make the assumption that consumers maximize their satisfaction, they include such seemingly altruistic activities among the choices consumers face.

People Make Choices at the Margin

The third thing that sets economics apart from other disciplines is that in economics, we argue that most choices are made “at the margin.” The is the current level of an activity. Think of it as the “edge” from which a choice is to be made. A is a decision to do a little more or a little less of something.

Here’s an example of a choice made at the margin: Imagine you pull into the drive-thru at your favorite fast-food joint. You scan the menu and see the following:

MENU
Burger$5
Drink$2
Fries$2

Based on those prices, the cash in your wallet, and your particular preferences, you decide to get a burger and a drink; the fries just aren’t worth the $2. And then, the clown’s mouth asks you an all-important question, a question you’ve probably often been asked: “Would you like burger/fry/drink combo meal for $8?”

“Would you like fries with that?” is a question no longer reserved just for fast-food workers!

Photo of a McDonalds fast food worker holding out a bag of food and a drink to a customer. The worker is smiling.

This is an interesting question—you’ve now got a new option to evaluate, one that wasn’t even on the menu! And notice that you don’t really have to think about whether the combo meal is worth the $8, because you’ve already committed to a $7 purchase of a burger and drink either way. Instead, all you have to determine is whether the extra food (fries) is worth the extra money (now $1 rather than $2!). The idea of only evaluating extra or additional costs and benefits in decision-making is the essence of marginal thinking, and the good news is that such marginal thinking will automatically guide you to the best choice between just the burger and drink or the combo meal.

Evaluating choices at the margin can lead to extremely useful insights. Consider, for example, the problem of curtailing water consumption when, say, a drought makes water increasingly scarce. Economists argue that one way to induce people to conserve water is to raise its price. But non-economists often disagree with this assessment, claiming that prices won’t affect water consumption because water is a necessity.

But choices in water consumption, like virtually all choices, are made at the margin. Individuals don’t make all-or-nothing decisions about whether they should or should not consume water. Instead, they decide whether to consume a little more or a little less water. For example, the typical person in the United States uses about 100 gallons of water each day. If the price of water doubled, could some of those people cut consumption to, say, 95 gallons per day by taking slightly shorter showers, or maybe flushing less often? High prices might also make people evaluate choices about what they use their water for: Few of us would eliminate toothbrushing at any price (we hope?), but many of us might stop washing our cars and watering our lawns with precious liquid gold. When we examine the choice to consume water at the margin, the notion that a higher  price would reduce consumption seems much more plausible. Prices affect our consumption of water because choices in water consumption, like other choices, are made at the margin.

You’re now acquainted with the three key elements of the economic way of thinking—opportunity cost, optimization, and decision-making at the margin. We’ll revisit and expand on these concepts repeatedly as we analyze the inner workings of the market system and the economy as a whole. 

Pop! Goes the Econ: Are Super Troopers Marginal Thinkers?

Find the marginal thinking (both costs and benefits) in this clip from the movie Super Troopers.

Microeconomics and Macroeconomics

Quick! Call a microeconomist—just got the bill for the popcorn!

Photo of a frightened couple eating popcorn in movie theater.

When you enrolled in your econ course, you probably signed up for either a “macro” or a “micro” course. If you’re uncertain what you’ve gotten yourself into (and don’t worry—most econ newbies are), you might find it helpful to know that economics is typically divided into two broad categories: microeconomics and macroeconomics. 

is the branch of economics that focuses on the choices made by individual decision-making units in the economy—typically consumers and firms—and the impacts those choices have on individual markets, like the market for cheese and the market for recorded music. In your micro course, you might dig into questions such as why tickets to the musical Hamilton cost so much, how global warming is affecting real estate prices, why women end up doing a disproportionate share of the housework, and why popcorn costs so much at the movies.

is the branch of economics that focuses on the impact of choices on the total, or aggregate, level of economic activity. Rather than looking at what’s happening in just the cheese market or just the market for bottled water, macroeconomists look at the big picture and attempt to measure and evaluate the performance of all markets—the cheese market, the bottled water market, the markets for sports merchandise and gasoline and hundreds of thousands of other goods and services—all at the same time. Is overall production in the United States rising or falling? What’s happening to the cost of living—and why? How will the unemployment rate change this month? These are the questions that macroeconomists attempt to answer. And those answers are important: Policymakers rely on macroeconomists to help them in their attempts to steer the broad economy toward desirable goals such as economic growth and the full employment of workers.

Putting Economics to Work

You now have a passing acquaintance with the types of issues economists address, and the types of questions economists are interested in answering. You’re also acquainted with some of the building blocks of economics: scarcity, opportunity cost, and marginal analysis. But you may still be curious about what it is that economists actually do. Is economics something a person can actually make a living doing?

Yes! Because the economic way of thinking has proven to be both insightful and useful, training in economics can be put to work in a wide range of fields. Of course, people with training in econ can become economists (we’ll talk briefly about what that entails in a second), but even if you don’t want to become an economist, you’ll find the economic training extremely useful both in other careers and in your personal life.

Careers in Economics

Suppose you decide to become an economist. Where can you find a job? Economists work in all kinds of places, but most of those places can be generally categorized in one of three ways: government agencies, business firms, and colleges and universities.

One dollar out of every five that gets spent in the economy is spent by some unit of government—either federal, state, or local. For all the highbrow talk about the dignity of public service, most government work reduces to making decisions about how to bring in tax money and then how to send it out again. In other words, your legislators, your governors, your president are all making the same kinds of choices you make about your own income and expenditures, but on a much larger scale. Governments employ economists to help them make decisions about how to spend this money: “Will we get the biggest bang for our buck building a border wall, or should we spend that money on an aircraft carrier?” Governments also employ economists to help them forecast economic activity, to measure the cost of living and other important variables, and to advise them on matters of policy: “If we give each taxpayer a $1,200 tax rebate, how many retail jobs will be saved?” or “Will more support for Head Start pre-K programs increase future SAT scores?”

Pop! Goes the Econ: The Relentless Pursuit of Greater Efficiency

That state of the art Xbox Kinect you loved so much? Economists were using that same technology a hundred years ago to improve efficiency in manufacturing! 

Economists work for businesses, too, and businesses beyond the stereotypical Wall Street firms like Goldman Sachs and Deutschebank. Hallmark employs economists to forecast sales of greeting cards. World Series champions employ economists to help them strategically price their tickets. BMW employs economists to help develop more efficient production processes (remember the choice of human power vs. robot power we talked about earlier? That’s just one piece of building the greatest number of cars out of the fewest resources). And economists’ training makes them particularly well suited for the rapidly growing field of data analytics, where the exploding world of internet data is used to determine the best location for a new Walgreens, Netflix’s best recommendations for those who loved The Good Place,  and the best products for Amazon to discount on Cyber Monday.

But we’re getting ahead of ourselves. After all, you’re young, and you probably haven’t met many industry or government economists yet. The economists you know probably work at your college or university. And yes, colleges and universities employ thousands and thousands of economists. In addition to teaching you about economic theory, those economists help guide your senior theses; they help faculty members in other disciplines crunch numbers for research projects; they conduct research projects of their own. In fact, the most brilliant economists in the world aren’t found on Wall Street or at the Federal Reserve; you’ll find most of our Nobel laureates in economics in university classrooms, teaching students by day and cultivating brilliance by night.  

Applying Economics to Other Fields

Okay, but I don’t really want to become an economist. I’m just taking this course because it’s required for my Social Influencing minor. Will training in econ still be useful?

While we’re sorry you’re not really interested in becoming a working economist, the good news is that your time in the econ classroom isn’t likely to be wasted. The economic way of thinking is both insightful and incisive; it helps people in all kinds of professions to make better decisions.

Suppose, for example, that you are considering law school. The study of law requires keen analytical skills; studying economics sharpens such skills. Not only do students with training in economics tend to do better in law school than students who lack such training, but students with econ training tend to have an easier time getting into law school in the first place!

One of the big litmus tests aspiring law students must pass is getting a good score on the Law School Admission Test (LSAT). Because econ students are taught to think carefully and logically through somewhat messy problems, year after year, students with economics training excel on this exam. That excellence is summarized in Table 1.1, which shows scores by major for entering law school students. 

Table 1.1 LSAT Scores for Students Taking the Exam in 2017–2018

Here are the average LSAT scores and rankings for the thirteen undergraduate majors with more than 1,000 students taking the test to enter law school in the 2017–2018 academic year.
Rank Major Average LSAT Score Number of Students
1 Economics 158.92,757
2 Philosophy 157.22,238
3 International Relations156.71,104
4 History 156.33,138
5 Finance 155.0 1,471
6English 154.8 3,151
7Political Science 153.611,947
8 Psychology 152.53,736
9 Business Marketing151.31,002
10 Communications 150.8 1,838
11 Sociology 150.6 1,870
12 Business Administration 149.3 1,489
13 Criminal Justice 145.9 3,629

Of course, you may not be interested in going to law school. But people with training in economics have lots of other great options and tend to do very well in terms of their lifetime earnings. The Georgetown Center on Education and the Workforce surveyed a large group of college graduates at various stages in their careers regarding both their earnings and their undergraduate major. Their study found that people with degrees in economics (but who weren’t necessarily working as economists) earned much more than people with degrees in the other social sciences. They also found economics to be the only non-STEM discipline among the top twenty-five highest-paid majors (that list is dominated by engineering and computer sciences). So whether you decide to become a production manager, an aircraft refurbisher, a personal financial planner, a baseball analyst, or a wedding planner, the skills you learn in the economics classroom will be both useful in advancing your career and financially rewarding.

Pop! Goes the Econ: Ferris Bueller’s Econ Teacher

Economists are multi-talented beasts. Get a double dose of economics in this clip from Ferris Bueller’s Day Off, as real-life economist-turned-law professor-turned actor-playing-teacher Ben Stein dazzles his students—with macroeconomics!

Of course, your choice of a major isn’t likely to be based solely on considerations of potential earnings or the prospect of landing a spot in law school. You are surely also considering your interests and abilities, and hopefully you’re also considering the benefits (both monetary and non-monetary) of other possible degree paths. What is your opportunity cost of pursuing a degree in economics? Does studying more economics serve your interests? Will doing so maximize your utility, now and over your lifetime? These considerations may be on your mind as you begin to study economics at the college level. But, should you decide to pursue further study in economics, you can rest assured that a background in this field is likely to serve you well.

Key Takeaways

  1. Economists focus on the opportunity costs of choices; they assume that individuals pursue their own self-interest and attempt to optimize their choices; and they assume that individuals make those choices at the margin.

  2. Economics is divided into two broad areas: microeconomics and macroeconomics.

  3. A wide range of career opportunities is open to economics majors. Empirical evidence suggests that students with a degree in economics tend to have an edge in getting into graduate programs and tend to have relatively high lifetime earnings.

Try It!

The Department of Agriculture estimated that the expenditures a middle-income, husband–wife family of three would incur to raise one additional child from birth in 2015 to age 17 would be $284,570. In what way does this estimate illustrate the economic way of thinking? Would the Department’s estimate be an example of microeconomic or of macroeconomic analysis? Why?

See related Concept Problem 10 at the end of this chapter.

Case in Point: Opportunity Cost with The Simpsons

Photo of two fingers with art drawn on them. Each finger is decorated with a sad face and an arm holding half of a broken heart.

In the animated television comedy The Simpsons, Homer’s father, Grampa Simpson, faced a classic problem in the allocation of a scarce resource—his time. He wanted to spend the day with his girlfriend, Bea—it was, after all, her birthday. His alternative was to spend the day with Homer and the family, which he did not really want to do, partly because they never visited him anyway.

Homer and his family prevailed, however, and insisted on taking Grampa to “Discount Lion Safari,” a local amusement park. The cost of Grampa’s day with his family is the enjoyment he anticipated from spending time with Bea. It all ends up badly for Grampa—Homer’s car breaks down on the way to the park. As for the forgone alternative, Bea dies that day, possibly because of a broken heart from not being able to spend the day with Grampa.

See related Concept Problem 8 at the end of this chapter.

Answer to Try It! Problem

The information given suggests one element of the economic way of thinking: assessing choices at the margin. The estimate reflects the cost of one additional child for a family that already has one. (Economists often use the words “extra” or “additional” as synonyms for the word “marginal.”)

It is not clear from the information given how close the estimate of cost comes to the economic concept of opportunity cost. The Department of Agriculture’s estimate included such costs as housing, food, transportation, clothing, health care, child care, and education. An economist would add the value of the best alternative use of the additional time that will be required to raise the child. If the couple is looking far ahead, it may want to consider the opportunity cost of sending that marginal child to college. And, if it is looking very far ahead, it may want to consider the fact that nearly half of all parents over the age of 50 support at least one child over the age of 21. This is a problem in microeconomic analysis, because it focuses on the choices of individual households.