1.2 Key Principles of Economics: Scarcity, Trade-Offs, and Opportunity Costs
Regardless of which system an economy chooses for organizing its production and distribution decisions, those decisions are governed by a common set of principles—principles that are the foundation on which this course is built. Understanding these principles will help you interpret news stories about the economy, make decisions about your life, and, importantly, succeed in this course.
Scarcity
The first of the key economic principles is scarcity. Scarcity A situation where limited resources make it impossible to fulfill all of our wants. means that we don’t have the resources necessary to fulfill all of our wants. One of the fundamental assumptions we’ll rely on in our study of economics is that our wants are virtually unlimited. We are born wanting: “Hey you—you in the white coat! It sure is cold and bright out here. Can you turn down the lights and turn up the thermostat?” We die wanting: “Please just give me a few more weeks to spend with my loved ones.” In between, we will spend a lifetime working to fulfill our material and spiritual wants: “I like my BMW, but would you look at the lines on the new Vette?” We’re fighting a losing battle. Our desires are virtually unlimited, but the means to satisfy those desires are not. The most obvious resource we’re lacking is cash: Most of us simply don’t have enough money to buy everything we would like. But a lack of money is often just a symptom of more fundamental resource shortfalls. For example, it generally takes some extraordinary ability to become super rich. Most people lack the athletic ability of LeBron James, the technological genius of Elon Musk, the market savvy of Warren Buffett, or the entrepreneurial vision of Jeff Bezos. And plain hard work can’t generally make up for the lack of those talents because, after all, we only have a limited amount of time on this planet; it just may not be enough.
In fact, time is one of our scarcest resources. If only we could work more hours to satisfy our material wants. If only we had more quality time to spend with our friends and family. If only we could pack a few extra hours into each day, how much happier we might be! But time is both precious and fleeting. A lack of time can make you wish you could be in two places at once, force you to pull an all-nighter before a psychology final, and make you angry about every second you spend stuck in traffic. In this way, time is the great equalizer: Wealthy people like Buffett and Bezos get the same 24 hours the rest of us do; even they feel the pressure of “not enough.”
The Great Equalizer
Apple founder Steve Jobs had more resources than most, yet he still couldn’t satisfy all of his wants. Discuss the notion of scarcity in this fascinating and eye-opening commencement address, then preview the next section and relate scarcity and opportunity cost.
Trade-Offs and Opportunity Costs
Because of scarcity, we have to make choices about which desires to satisfy and which to leave unfulfilled. Nobody gets to break the law of scarcity, no matter where they live or what system their economy is based on. We all face trade-offs in that we address some needs at the expense of others. Economists have a special term for trade-offs: opportunity costs. The opportunity cost What is sacrificed in order to engage in an activity. of an activity is what you sacrifice to engage in that activity. At its most basic, opportunity cost is a straightforward concept. Suppose you’re down to your last $15, and there are two things you really want to do. One is to see the new Black Panther sequel at the movie theater, and the other is to eat a rack of ribs at the local barbecue joint. But each of these activities costs about $15, so you can afford one or the other, but you can’t afford both. If you choose the movie, you lose the opportunity to eat a great meal. If you choose the meal, you give up the opportunity to see the movie. The option you don’t choose is the opportunity cost of your choice.
It is, of course, true that when you decide to go to the movie, you lose other alternatives as well. With the $15 you spend on your movie ticket, you could have gotten a great rack of ribs. But you could also have downloaded the latest Olivia Rodrigo album, put a few gallons of gas in your car, or enjoyed a monster-sized half-caf caramel latte. It is, however, inaccurate to say that because you went to the movie you gave up a meal, a CD, five gallons of gas, and a latte, because $15 would have allowed you to buy any one of those things but not all of those things. So, when we talk about measuring the cost of what we gave up, we consider the best of the sacrificed options as the opportunity cost. This is why many economists describe the opportunity cost of doing something as “the value of your next-best alternative.”
The concept of opportunity cost applies to individuals, but it also applies to groups—from small groups like households to large groups like countries. For example, because resources are scarce, countries have to decide what they will produce and what they won’t. Not every country can do everything well: If Finland decides it wants to grow bananas, it’s going to have to pump a lot of resources into building, staffing, and heating greenhouses—resources that could have been used to produce other things like softwood lumber and cellular phones. In other words, bananas are expensive in Finland in that they are grown at high opportunity cost. In contrast, bananas are pretty easy to grow in Guatemala, and their opportunity cost is relatively low. Because of its warm climate and a relative lack of skilled labor, the resources used to produce bananas in Guatemala wouldn’t be very productive if they were devoted to growing pine trees or making cell phones instead. Such differences in opportunity costs create natural opportunities for countries to gain by trading with one another: Finland can send Guatemala some of its cell phones in exchange for some of Guatemala’s bananas. That keeps each country from trying to do something that it’s not particularly good at. (That process of exchange is explored in greater depth in Chapter 5 “Free Exchange: Individual and International Trade”.)
Opportunity Cost Is Not About Money
When you talk with your friends about how much your last pedicure cost, you probably measure that cost in dollars. So, our movie-versus-meal example may puzzle you. Couldn’t we simply say that the movie cost $15 and avoid discussing the ribs?
Economists avoid measuring opportunity cost strictly in terms of money for two reasons. First, as strange as it sounds, money itself does not make us particularly happy. Our money—ones, fives, tens, twenties, fifties, and c-notes—is a contrivance we invented to help facilitate exchange. It has virtually no intrinsic value. It is simply colorful paper, backed by only the expectation that if we accept it in exchange for the things we sell, we will later be able to find someone else to accept it in exchange for the things we wish to buy. That’s particularly true when the thing we’re selling is our labor: We’re generally confident that we’ll be able to use the money we earn to buy clothes and food. If we weren’t, we’d demand to be paid in blue jeans and sushi.
It’s the clothes, and the food, and the other things we enjoy that really matter to us. If you run a $50 bill through the washing machine and it comes out in little linty pieces, you’re probably not upset the bill is gone. More likely, you’re upset because no longer can you use that bill to go out Saturday night with friends, buy books, or pay rent. Fundamentally, the loss of those opportunities is what is important; the loss of fancy colorful paper is not.
Opportunity Cost in How I Met Your Mother
In this clip from How I Met Your Mother, Barney faces a difficult trade-off. Preview the next section, then evaluate whether the cost of a suit is an explicit cost or an implicit cost.
The second reason economists sometimes avoid using money as a measure of opportunity cost is because not all opportunities are easily measured in dollars. Suppose it’s the night before your chemistry final. You’re just settling in for some intensive study when friends down the hall stop by to see if you’d like to join them to see The Rocky Horror Picture Show. “We’ve got an extra ticket,” they tell you. “One night only—and it won’t cost you a dime!”
And they’re right—it won’t cost you a dime, but it will cost you time. Once again, you’re facing a tough choice. If you decide to study, you’ll miss a cult classic and some time with your friends. If you go to the movie, you’ll sacrifice valuable study time—time that could easily make a difference in your course grade. The opportunity cost—the trade-off—is very real and very important to you, but it is not easily measured in dollars. So, when you consider your trade-offs, all costs matter, not just those that involve money.
Explicit Costs versus Implicit Costs
The distinction between costs that involve an exchange of cash and those that don’t is an important one. Explicit costs Costs that are measured in dollars and that typically involve some exchange of money. are costs that are measured in dollars and that typically involve some exchange of money. Implicit costs Costs that do not involve an exchange of money. are costs that do not involve an exchange of money. Implicit costs can sometimes be difficult to measure, but they are still real costs, and they are still important. When we evaluate trade-offs, accounting for explicit costs is fairly straightforward, but we want to take extra care to account for implicit costs.
Consider, for example, a new program at your university that will provide all students free Subway sandwiches at lunchtime each semester. This may seem like a great deal to you. But is the free lunch program really free to you? After all, Subway isn’t going to give those sandwiches away. One way that your university might fund the sandwich program is by raising your tuition. In that case, the costs are explicit, and those costs represent the other things you might have spent those tuition dollars on—possibly things you might like more than a few hundred sandwiches.
But your university might choose to hold the line on tuition and not pass the cost of the sandwich program along to you explicitly. That doesn’t mean that the sandwich program doesn’t cost you something! For starters, you’re likely to spend lots of time standing in line waiting for your “free” sandwiches. That’s an implicit cost, and it may be very important to you.
You might bear the cost in more subtle ways. Perhaps the expense of the sandwich program forces the university to make cuts elsewhere. Maybe it will hire fewer professors and, as a result, a course that you’ll need in order to graduate won’t be offered on schedule. Or perhaps your university will cut the midmorning section of General Psych you were hoping to take, leaving only a 7:30 a.m. section that costs you hours of valuable sleep.
These implicit costs are very real. They matter to you. But even though they’re a direct consequence of the sandwich program, that fact is not readily apparent to a casual observer. This is because the sandwich program is one of many university programs, and it can be hard to link cause and effect when all those programs get jumbled together. But more important is the fact that it’s hard to account for those implicit costs using dollars because they are opportunities that never materialized. Figuring out the size of those lost opportunities is just plain tough.
In the end, though, one conclusion is certain: Your university’s sandwich program is not free. Somebody pays, visibly or invisibly, directly or indirectly, for every sandwich eaten. And that someone is likely to be you. This example demonstrates why the most famous saying in all of economics, popularized by the late Nobel Prize–winning economist Milton Friedman, is, “There is no such thing as a free lunch.” That wisdom, which is often referred to as the “law of no free lunch,” applies to you, your university, and everyone else.
Application 1.1: Even Superheroes Face Trade-Offs
Everyone faces trade-offs. You face them. Presidents face them. Even dictators face them. But you, presidents, and dictators are mere mortals. Could it be that superheroes, with their superpowers, don’t fall prey to the laws of scarcity?
Alas, even superheroes face trade-offs. To illustrate, consider Superman. He can’t be in two places at once. So when Lois Lane is being mugged on the south side of Metropolis, and arch-villain Lex Luthor is kidnapping Daily Planet editor Perry White on the north side, Superman has to make a choice: Will he save Lois, or will he save Perry?
If Superman is really interested in saving lives, perhaps he should let Lois be mugged and let Perry be kidnapped, and instead use his powers to benefit even greater numbers of people. What if society put Superman to work plowing fields in impoverished countries, or hauling water to irrigate crops in drought-stricken regions? What if Superman used his strength to turn a gigantic generator, creating electricity that raises living standards across the globe, or that saves lives by powering dialysis machines and respirators? That would surely be a better use of Superman’s strength than having him waiting around for an isolated crime or two to occur in relatively wealthy Metropolis.
Because instead, Superman chooses to fight crime one villain at a time, society loses. And because of the daunting trade-offs they face, Superman and his fellow crime fighters also lose. The demands of the job are so incredible, regardless of what tasks these superheroes undertake, that their chances of having normal relationships are slim. Consider the fact that very few superheroes reveal their true identity to their love interests: To keep their loved ones from being used against them, they’re forced to hide their super-selves from their friends, their families, and the world as a whole, often behind a mask. That lack of openness and honest communication takes its toll. Superman loved Lois Lane, Batman loved Vicky Vale, Spider-Man loved Mary Jane Watson, and Wonder Woman has had many love interests over the years. Yet each of those relationships was a rocky, drawn-out affair, and in the end, only Superman ended up with his true love.
Everyone faces trade-offs, including superheroes. Superpowers may enable superheroes to defy the law of gravity, but even superpowers aren’t strong enough to break the law of scarcity.
Refer to related problem 6 at the end of this section.
Government, Public Policy, and Trade-Offs
The “law of no free lunch” also applies to governments. Some problems, such as pollution and poverty, can be difficult for individuals to solve on their own. Governments can help solve such problems but, like individuals, governments face opportunity costs. A government can’t provide us with everything we desire; its resources are limited, and our desires are not. For a given amount of revenue, your government must decide which goods or services to provide for people and which ones people will have to provide for themselves. A harsh winter that requires government to spend a lot of money plowing highways could mean cutting back on summer programs for children. Buying more tanks and fighter jets for the military could mean less government funding for national parks.
Governments aren’t always the best at solving our problems. In fact, sometimes governments can actually make things worse. A government that expends resources trying to solve problems that people can solve for themselves may be wasting those resources. A government that actually makes things worse through its actions definitely is. Throughout this book, we’ll explore questions of public policy. Public policy The collection of laws, regulatory measures, and actions concerning a particular topic that originates with some body of government. is the collection of laws, regulatory measures, and actions concerning a particular topic, such as the environment or health care, that originates with some body of government.
In other words, public policy concerns the collection of choices the government makes. We’ll spend considerable time evaluating those choices: Is the government using its scarce resources where they can do the most good? Is it applying its powers to improve society? Or is it squandering its resources by applying them to problems that can be better solved in other ways? Further, governments, policymakers, and politicians have their own sets of motivations that may not align well with society’s interests. Some politicians, for example, might devote more effort to pursuing reelection and raising soft money than they spend trying to pass legislation and improving society. The public choice branch of economics applies the same set of tools economists use to study the motivations of buyers and sellers to examine the self-interested behavior of politicians, lobbyists, agencies, bureaucrats, and voters.
Determining the best public policy options is often difficult because many government trade-offs are implicit, which makes them subtle and difficult to measure. Consider, for example, the automobile safety regulation “Click It or Ticket,” which requires people to wear safety belts. One benefit of the regulation is that it encourages people to use the safety equipment in their cars. Consequently, they will be more likely to survive a crash.
More crash survivors? That sounds like a no-brainer! But even something that seems so good at first glance comes with trade-offs. In this case, the trade-off is that mandatory seat belt regulations reduce the cost of driving like a maniac: Belted drives face a lower risk of injury or death, smaller hospital bills, and less pain. Because of that, we can expect some people to drive faster, venture out more often when roads are icy, and pay less attention while driving. As a result, mandatory seat belt laws may actually create more accidents. And people—both pedestrians and occupants of other cars—will die in those accidents. This puts government in the odd position of choosing exactly who it is going to save: “We know the new law will save the lives of drivers who get in accidents, but we also know that the new law will end up causing some entirely innocent people to die in accidents that would otherwise not have occurred. If we pass the law, we save X number of lives; if we don’t pass the law, we’ll save Y number of lives.” Now that’s a deadly trade-off! (Chapter 2 “Cost–Benefit Analysis and the Value of a Life” talks in greater detail about these deadly trade-offs.)
In the case of mandatory seat belt laws, the trade-off is subtle but measurable. The government has numbers to work with: It can compare X and Y and figure out, based on their magnitudes, whether the law produces a net gain. In fact, governments regularly employ economists and statisticians to do just that—estimate how many lives might be both saved and lost as a result of such a policy and make a recommendation based on those estimates.
Sometimes measuring trade-offs can be more difficult. Consider, for example, the U.S. Constitution’s protection of free speech. As a society, we value free speech because it gives us the right to express ourselves without fear of sanction by the government. But free speech doesn’t come without cost; there’s always a trade-off. Free speech gives you the right to speak your mind, but it also gives someone who is loudmouthed, anti-Semitic, misogynistic, and economist-hating the right to speak his. That trade-off isn’t particularly subtle, but the costs and benefits are very hard to quantify.
Application 1.2: Zero-COVID . . . Forever?
Economically speaking, everything was going so well! In the U.S., unemployment was at a record low; inflation hovered just below 2%; the stock market had just hit all-time highs. It was January of 2020, and it seemed as though nothing could dampen the economy’s collective exuberance.
And then, the novel coronavirus made an unwelcome appearance. As the spring unfolded, different countries crafted different responses to deal with the challenge of a virus that had proven very real and very deadly. New Zealand and Australia sealed their external borders. The developed nations of the EU adopted strict limits on social gatherings and sent workers in non-essential sectors home. The U.S. largely followed the EU lead, closing borders to outsiders and empowering individual states to mandate mask requirements and furlough non-essential workers. Sweden, in contrast, adopted a relatively relaxed set of restrictions, drawing a fair amount of criticism from the global community in response.
And then there was China. With a high population density that made transmission particularly dangerous, China’s authoritarian government adopted a “zero-COVID” approach, imposing strict lockdowns, mandatory testing, forced quarantines, and rigorous contact tracing at the first sign of the virus’s spread.
As spring gave way to summer, it became clear that people had different tolerances for restrictions. COVID became a political issue in the U.S., and states began relaxing restrictions in patchwork fashion. The unemployment rate, which had spiked to over 14% in March 2020 began to work its way back down again as the economy returned to “business as (un)usual.” Countries around the world were also slowly relaxing restrictions; as they did, the virus spread, and cases, hospitalizations, and deaths mounted.
Fast-forward three years to a world that had been through several huge COVID spikes, a world with new and highly effective vaccines. Exposure to the virus and vaccination had given most people a degree of immunity that allowed them to resume normal living. Even countries with the most stringent COVID controls, like Australia and New Zealand (who closed their external borders for two entire years), had largely resumed the rhythms of normal life.
And then there was China, where zero-COVID was still the rule. Three years into the pandemic, in an era that most of the world now referred to as “post-COVID,” frequent strict lockdowns continued to disrupt the lives of billions of people, slowing economic growth to a crawl and weakening a global supply chain that the rest of the world depended on. Those economic disruptions, along with the loss of individual freedom of movement and association that the rest of the world had largely regained, spawned intense protests as 2022 drew to a close.
Of course, China adopted zero-COVID for a reason: to save lives. In the first three years of the pandemic, the global COVID death rate had averaged about 850 per million residents. But not every country had the same experience. Generally speaking, countries that rolled back restrictions the earliest also paid the highest price. In early-relaxing countries like the U.S. and Brazil, there were over 3,000 COVID deaths for every million residents. In New Zealand and Australia, relatively late to remove restrictions, there were only 600. And China, the last holdout in the global battle against COVID? After three years of battling the virus, China’s death rate wasn’t 3,000 per million, or even 300 per million. It was an astonishing four!
Ironically, China’s freedom from COVID, won largely by its heavy-handed approach to managing the disease, was the very reason China found itself unable to relax its policies and resume normal life. With so few cases, a low vaccination rate, and access only to less-effective locally produced vaccines, the typical resident had acquired little ability to resist the disease. A large outbreak could easily overwhelm the Chinese health care system, much as had happened in Hong Kong in early 2022. And so, having metaphorically painted itself into a corner, China was left with only two choices: soldier on in its war against COVID, or walk through the paint and fall in step with the rest of the world.
Refer to related problems 2, 3, 4, and 9 at the end of this section.
Key Takeaways
Several key principles govern all of economics. First, all of society’s decisions are made in an environment of scarcity.
Because of scarcity, we have to sacrifice some options to take advantage of others.
The opportunity cost of an action is the value of the next best option sacrificed, whether that value is measurable in dollars or not.
Review Questions
means that society doesn’t have enough resources to produce the things it wants.
To date Michelle, you break up with Susan. Losing Susan is called the of dating Michelle.
You pay $5 for a slice of pizza. That $5 is called an cost.
You purchase a new backpack for $75. The cash you sacrificed is a(n) .
explicit cost
implicit cost
deferred cost
accrued cost
You decide to spend spring break digging wells in developing countries and forgo the chance to spend a week on the beach with your friends in Panama City. Losing the chance to be with your friends is the cost of digging wells.
explicit
implicit
deferred
inherent
When evaluating options, good economists consider .
only explicit costs and benefits
only implicit costs and benefits
both implicit and explicit costs and benefits
neither implicit nor explicit costs and benefits
Who does not face trade-offs?
You
Super-rich CEOs of high-powered corporations
The U.S. government
Everybody faces trade-offs.
While Superman sits around Metropolis waiting to save Lois Lane from Lex Luthor, he sacrifices the opportunity to generate electricity for millions. That forgone opportunity is a(n) cost of protecting Lois Lane.
implicit
explicit
monetary
sunk
Problems and Applications
Going to college is an expensive proposition. List the basic explicit costs of attending college. Be sure not to include explicit costs you would face anyway, such as food or housing. Then consider the implicit costs of attending college: What opportunity did you pass up, and how much was that opportunity worth? Finally, add implicit and explicit costs to determine the full opportunity cost of attending college.
[Related to Application 1.2] Explain the trade-off between lives and prosperity that nations faced during the early days of the coronavirus. How did different nations assess this trade-off? Is it possible, reasonable, or ethical to put a dollar value on human life? Discuss.
[Related to Application 1.2] Explain the trade-off between that short run and the long run that China’s zero-COVID policy created. How would you have evaluated that trade-off?
[Related to Application 1.2] One cost of stricter public policy approaches to battling COVID is the loss of individual freedoms—freedom from masks; freedom of commerce; freedom of movement. Why is it hard to weigh those costs against the benefits of fewer cases, hospitalizations, and deaths? Do people in some places value those freedoms more highly than people in others?
The National Security Agency (NSA) came under attack in 2014 for monitoring individuals’ cell phone calls. Discuss the trade-offs of this NSA surveillance.
In 2017, Luis Fonsi’s “Despacito” video became the most popular video on YouTube. Count the number of views and multiply by the length of the video to determine how much time has been spent watching Fonsi’s video. Express your answer in hours and then convert to years. If the Empire State Building took 7 million labor-hours to complete, what is the opportunity cost of “Despacito,” expressed in Empire State Buildings?
In 2017, President Donald Trump proposed building a border wall to reduce illegal immigration. The estimated cost of the wall, which would span most of the U.S.–Mexican border, was about $20 billion. Describe the opportunity cost of that wall by enumerating other programs the federal government might be interested in funding in similar amounts.
[Related to Application 1.1]. View this clip from the 2002 movie Spider-Man. Describe the immediate trade-off Spider Man faces. Then, think about the “big-picture” trade-off Peter Parker faces in becoming a superhero. Do you suppose society is made better off for his choices?
[Related to Application 1.2]. Following mass protests in late 2022, China relaxed its Zero-COVID regime, resulting in a large spike in COVID cases and COVID deaths. Discuss the trade-offs in this reversal. Why do you suppose the government felt it necessary to change course?